Competition and The Operational Performance of Hospitals: The Role of Hospital Objectives

Competition and The Operational Performance of Hospitals: The Role of Hospital Objectives

0.00 Avg rating0 Votes
Article ID: iaor2016459
Volume: 24
Issue: 11
Start Page Number: 1812
End Page Number: 1832
Publication Date: Nov 2015
Journal: Production and Operations Management
Authors: ,
Keywords: performance, quality & reliability, game theory, queues: applications
Abstract:

We examine the effect of a hospital's objective (i.e., non‐profit vs. for‐profit) in hospital markets for elective care. Using game‐theoretic analysis and queueing models to capture the operational performance of hospitals, we compare the equilibrium behavior of three market settings in terms of such criteria as waiting times and patient costs from waiting and hospital payments. In the first setting, a monopoly, patients are served exclusively by a single non‐profit hospital; in the second, a homogeneous duopoly, patients are served by two competing non‐profit hospitals. In our third setting, a heterogeneous duopoly, the market is served by one non‐profit hospital and one for‐profit hospital. A non‐profit hospital provides free care to patients, although they may have to wait; for‐profit hospitals charge a fee to provide care with minimal waiting. A comparison between the monopolistic and each of the duopolistic settings reveals that the introduction of competition can hamper a hospital's ability to attain economies of scale and can also increase waiting times. Moreover, the presence of a for‐profit sector may be desirable only when the hospital market is sufficiently competitive. A comparison across the duopolistic settings indicates that the choice between homogeneous and heterogeneous competition depends on the patients' willingness to wait before receiving care and the reimbursement level of the non‐profit sector. When the public funder is not financially constrained, the presence of a for‐profit sector may allow the funder to lower both the financial costs of providing coverage and the total costs to patients. Finally, our analysis suggests that the public funder should exercise caution when using policy tools that support the for‐profit sector–for example, patient subsidies–because such tools may increase patient costs in the long run; it might be preferable to raise the non‐profit sector's level of reimbursement.

Reviews

Required fields are marked *. Your email address will not be published.